References for Journalarticle economics

Please note: the authoritative source for references in this article is the according PDF file.

Number of references: 29

Aoki, M., and Yoshikawa, H. (2007). Non-Self-Averaging in Macroeconomic Models: A Criticism of Modern Micro-founded Macroeconomics. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 1(2007-49).

Aoki, M., and Yoshikawa, H. (2007). Reconstructing Macroeconomics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Ariely, D. (2008). Predictably Irrational. New York: Harper Collins Publishers.

Arthur, W.B. (1994). Inductive Reasoning and Bounded Rationality. American Economic Review, 84:406-411.

Bechara, A., and Damasio, A.R. (2005). The Somatic Marker Hypothesis: A Neural Theory of Economic Decision. Games and Economic Behavior, 52:336-372.

Bliss, C.J. (1975). Capital Theory and the Distribution of Income. New York: Elsevier.

Buchanan, M. (2007). The Social Atom. New York: Bloomsbury Publishing.

Camerer, C., G. Loewenstein, and Prelec, D. (2005). Neuroeconomics: How Neuroscience Can Inform Economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 43:9-64.

Delli Gatti, D., Gaffeo, E., Giulioni, M., and Palestrini, A. (2008). Emergent Macroeconomics. Milan: Springer.

Estrella, A., and Fuhrer, J.C. (2003). Monetary Policy Shifts and the Stability of Monetary Policy Models. Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(1):94-104.

Gabaix, X. (2008). Power Laws in Economics and Finance. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 14299.

Geweke, J. (1985). Macroeconometric Modeling and the Theory of the Representative Agent. The American Economic Review, 75(2):206-210.

Janssen, M.C.W. (2008). Microfoundations. In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, ed. by S.N. Durlauf and L.E. Blume, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

Kirman, A.P. (1992). Whom or What Does the Representative Individual Represent? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6:117-136.

Krugman, P.R. (1996). The Self-Organizing Economy. Oxford: Blackwell.

Lindé, J. (2001). Testing for the Lucas Critique: A Quantitative Investigation. American Economic Review, 91:986-1005.

Lubik, T.A., and Surico, P. (2006). The Lucas Critique and the Stability of Empirical Models. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Working Paper 06−05.

Lucas, R.E. (1976). Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 1:19-46.

Lucas, R.E., and Sargent, T. (1981). After Keynesian Macroeconomics. In: Rational Expectations and Econometric Practice, ed. by R.E. Lucas and T. Sargent, pp. 295-319, University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis.

Mantegna, R.N., and Stanley, H.E. (2000). An Introduction to Econophysics. Cambridge University Press.

Platt, M.L., and Huettel, S.A. (2008). Risky Business: The Neuroeconomics of Decision Making under Uncertainty. Nature Neuroscience, 11:398-403.

Robson, A. (2001). The Biological Basis of Economic Behavior. Journal of Economic Literature, 39(1):11-33.

Rotemberg, J.J. (1987). The New Keynesian Microfoundations. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 2:69-104.

Rudebusch, G.D. (2005). Assessing the Lucas Critique in Monetary Policy Models. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 37:245-272.

Scarth, W.M. (1988). Macroeconomics. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, Toronto.

Schelling, T.C. (1978). Micromotives and Macrobehavior. W.W. Norton, New York.

Sonnenschein, H. (1973). Do Walras' Identity and Continuity Characterize the Class of Community Excess Demand Functions? Journal of Economic Theory, 6(4):345 - 354.

Sowell, T. (1974). Classical Economics Reconsidered. Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Trepel, C., Fox, C.R., and Poldrack, R.A. (2005). Prospect Theory on the Brain? Toward a Cognitive Neuroscience of Decision under Risk. Cognitive Brain Research, 23:34-50.